Forex policy of india

Forex policy of india

Posted: Petr_B On: 01.07.2017

The strategy to pursue export-led growth anchored upon an undervalued exchange rate policy, which had no takers. There was equanimity about pegging the exchange rate to a currency basket.

forex policy of india

But China had picked up the cue from Asian Tigers, silently devising a new growth strategy centered upon an undervalued exchange rate to propel exports. Its success is now a folklore: How did China manage to sustain a weak currency for so many years despite a regular current account surplus for decades? Any such strategy would raise two important macroeconomic questions about inflation and stability: And two, how did the Chinese government handle the exchange rate pass-through to domestic inflation, for China depended heavily on oil and raw material imports for its industry?

The answer to the first question is that ample fiscal space was created to absorb the intervention costs. Fiscal prudence helped keep debt-GDP ratios fairly moderate, with an eye on high credit-rating. Simultaneously, forex reserves were strategically deployed to extract maximum returns, economic and political.

Renaissance Literary & Talent

The critical part, however, relates to the exchange rate pass-through impacts upon domestic inflation. China mitigated this by deep structural reforms in both agriculture and industry, maintaining productivity growth over a long period.

Reserve Bank of India issues guidance on foreign exchange rules - EY - Global

In particular, it managed to consistently raise cereal crop yields since the s, which helped contain food inflation despite the manifold jump in demand. Labour productivity in industry leaped as FDI was directed to the tradable sector.

The remarkable feature here is how the Chinese authorities did not allow currency appreciation throughout these years even when domestic-foreign inflation differentials were minimal, while productivity growth much higher than the trading partners. Our planners opted for a gradual weakening of the currency within a narrow band until the balance-of-payments crisis, which forced a major devaluation. In , the rupee became fully convertible on the current account.

The post reforms and a relatively freer exchange rate regime did create an optimistic environment for exports, but gains were tepid as the Asian crisis unfolded. Post-Asian crisis, Indian policymakers quickly ushered in significant capital account liberalisation even before the exporting sector could secure a sound foothold. Gushes of capital inflows forced premature currency appreciation that affected competitiveness, even while the economy ran persistent current account deficits.

China meanwhile, as the folklore goes, became the global leader, increasing its share of world exports to an astounding The probing question then is, why did India balk at the Chinese approach of exporting its way to growth through an undervalued currency when global trade was expanding at a rapid pace?

Why did we shy away from a course that China so successfully traversed, ie, building and expanding a tradable sector for rapid growth and mass creation of jobs to draw out millions engaged in low-productivity agriculture? Why the aversion to a weak rupee? The point can be elucidated by raising a few questions.

The obvious answer is the lack of fiscal space to bear the costs of liquidity absorption. Competitive calls for social sector expenditure on top of high debt-GDP levels left little scope for creating fiscal space for long-term strategic intervention.

This left RBI with no option except to calibrate forex intervention operations consistent with the desired growth in its balance sheet and the monetary base.

Any surplus, naturally, ended in pushing up the exchange rate. What if the government had been open to the idea of fully absorbing the costs of forex intervention? Would RBI have gone ahead and built forex reserves of a trillion dollar or so, letting the rupee persistently drift downwards as was the case with the Renminbi?

If yes, how would the government have handled the inflation fallout arising from the exchange rate pass-through? An effective response to such long-term stability concerns would then have required significant productivity increases. The answers, therefore, would certainly lie in the political economy domain—the ability for deep structural reforms.

India's Foreign Exchange Reserves: Policy, Status and Issues on JSTOR

Unfortunately, the reform track record on this does not inspire much confidence. Unlike China, India could not reform agriculture to consistently raise crop yields in response to food price inflation; agriculture reforms could not extend beyond the Green Revolution.

Even after three decades, India has been unable to meaningfully touch factor market reforms, even as those in the product markets have remained incomplete. Efforts to build world class infrastructure spluttered midway. Stuck with structural rigidities and inadequate supply responses, any strategy to anchor an undervalued currency upon export growth would be fraught with high macro-instability risks, thus remaining out of bounds for policymakers.

To the contrary, policymakers, including the RBI, have often swung to the other end of the pendulum, ie, delving into bouts of currency appreciation by relaxing the capital account.

Foreign Trade Policy Lectures No.1 on Legal Framework and Trade Facilitations by gepahotalefi.web.fc2.com Tayal

The fallout has been an over-reliance upon demand-side management that does not even shy away from exchange rate-based stabilisation. Willy-nilly, RBI too ended up using the exchange rate as an instrument to fight imported inflation. What has India achieved with this approach to the exchange rate? We have had to subject ourselves to a new flexible inflation targeting FIT regime that could extract a significant sacrifice in growth.

Rupee: New dawn for RBI rupee policy? Lack of intervention leaves traders surprised

One would expect the new monetary policy regime would not deploy the exchange rate as a policy instrument. But the temptation could be there.

The central bank would be fighting a battle to gain credibility for its FIT framework, lower inflation expectations. The central bank must realize though that any overvaluation is a short term quick-fix; such actions have been more palliative, followed often by a weakening bout — the near-run on the rupee in being the latest piece of evidence.

One also hopes the government is not enticed by the false sense of improvement in fundamentals or associates a stronger currency with national pride. May 2, 4: The deficit must be reduced sharply to allow RBI to absorb liquidity arising from intervening in the currency market, and a productivity surge is needed to keep domestic inflation in check.

Will like to add that china resorted substantially to sterilized intervention and to administered interest rates to minimize its impact. International Yoga Day The Express Group The Indian Express The Financial Express Loksatta Jansatta inUth Ramnath Goenka Awards.

Privacy Policy Advertise with Us Contact Us Feedback.

Rating 4,1 stars - 403 reviews
inserted by FC2 system